Perfect competition and the supply curve 


Мы поможем в написании ваших работ!



ЗНАЕТЕ ЛИ ВЫ?

Perfect competition and the supply curve



A price-taking producer is a producer whose actions have no effect on the market price of the good or service it sells.

A price-taking consumer is a consumer whose actions have no effect on the market price of the good or service he or she buys.

A perfectly competitive market is a market in which all market participants are price-takers.

A perfectly competitive industry is an industry in which producers are price-takers.

A producer’s market share is the fraction of the total industry output accounted for by that producer’s output.

A good is a standardized product, also known as a commodity, when consumers regard the products of different producers as the same good.

An industry has free entry and exit when new producers can easily enter into an industry and existing producers can easily leave that industry.

Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue generated by an additional unit of output.

The optimal output rule says that profit is maximized by producing the quantity of output at which the marginal revenue of the last unit produced is equal to its marginal cost.

 

TR = P × Q Profit = TR − TC MR = ΔTR/ΔQ

 

 

The price-taking firm’s optimal output rule says that a price-taking firm’s profit is maximized by producing the quantity of output at which the market price is equal to the marginal cost of the last unit produced.

 

The marginal revenue curve shows how marginal revenue varies as output varies.

 

  • If the firm produces a quantity at which TR > TC, the firm is profitable.
  • If the firm produces a quantity at which TR = TC, the firm breaks even.
  • If the firm produces a quantity at which TR < TC, the firm incurs a loss.

 

Profit/ Q = TR / QTC / Q Profit=TR−TC=(TR/Q−TC/Q)×Q Profit = (P − ATC) × Q

 

  • If the firm produces a quantity at which P > ATC, the firm is profitable.
  • If the firm produces a quantity at which P = ATC, the firm breaks even.
  • If the firm produces a quantity at which P < ATC, the firm incurs a loss.

 

 

 

The break-even price of a price-taking firm is the market price at which it earns zero profits.

  • Whenever the market price exceeds minimum average total cost, the producer is profitable.
  • Whenever the market price equals minimum average total cost, the producer breaks even.
  • Whenever the market price is less than minimum average total cost, the producer is unprofitable.

 

The short-tun individual supply curve

 

A firm will cease production in the short run if the market price falls below the shut-down price, which is equal to minimum average variable cost.

The short-run individual supply curve shows how an individual producer’s profit-maximizing output quantity depends on the market price, taking fixed cost as given.

  • When the market price is below minimum average variable cost
  • When the market price is greater than or equal to minimum average variable cost

 

 

The industry supply curve shows the relationship between the price of a good and the total output of the industry as a whole.

The short-run industry supply curve shows how the quantity supplied by an industry depends on the market price given a fixed number of producers.

 

There is a short-run market equilibrium when the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded, taking the number of producers as given.

 

Short-run equilibrium

 

A market is in long-run market equilibrium when the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded, given that sufficient time has elapsed for entry into and exit from the industry to occur.

 

The long-run industry supply curve shows how the quantity supplied responds to the price once producers have had time to enter or exit the industry.

MONOPOLY

➤The significance of monopoly, where a single monopolist is the only producer of a good

➤ How a monopolist determines its profit-maximizing output and price

➤ The difference between monopoly and perfect competition, and the effects of that difference on society’s welfare

➤ How policy makers address the problems posed by monopoly

➤ What price discrimination is, and why it is so prevalent when producers have market power

In order to develop principles and make predictions about markets and how producers will behave in them, economists have developed four principal models of market structure:

1. perfect competition

2. monopoly

3. oligopoly

4. monopolistic competition.

 

The Meaning of Monopoly

A monopolist is a firm that is the only producer of a good that has no close substitutes. An industry controlled by a monopolist is known as a monopoly.

Market power is the ability of a firm to raise prices.


The reason a monopolist reduces output and raises price compared to the perfectly competitive industry levels is to increase profit. The monopoly would generate more profit than the sum of the profits of the individual competitive firms. Under monopoly the profits don’t go away—a monopolist is able to continue earning economic profits in the long run

To earn economic profits, a monopolist must be protected by a barrier to entry—something that prevents other firms from entering the industry.

1. Control of a Scarce Resource or Input A monopolist that controls a resource or input crucial to an industry can prevent other firms from entering its market.

2. Local gas supply is an industry in which average total cost falls as output increases – increasing returns to scale. There we learned that when average total cost falls as output increases, firms tend to grow larger. In an industry characterized by increasing returns to scale, larger companies are more profitable and drive out smaller ones. For the same reason, established companies have a cost advantage over any potential entrant—a potent barrier to entry. So increasing returns to scale can both give rise to and sustain monopoly.

 

A natural monopoly exists when increasing returns to scale provide a large cost advantage to a single firm that produces all of an industry’s output.

3. Technological Superiority A firm that maintains a consistent technological advantage over potential competitors can establish itself as a monopolist. But technological superiority is typically not a barrier to entry over the longer term: over time competitors will invest in upgrad- ing their technology to match that of the technology leader. however, that in certain high-tech industries, technological superiority is not a guarantee of success against competitors. Some high-tech industries are characterized by network externalities, a condition that arises when the value of a good to the consumer rises as the number of people who also use the good rises. In these industries, the firm possessing the largest network—the largest number of consumers currently using its product—has an advantage over its competitors in attracting new customers, an advantage that may allow it to become a monopolist.

4. The most important legally created monopolies today arise from patents and copy- rights. A patent gives an inventor a temporary monopoly in the use or sale of an invention. A copyright gives the creator of a liter- ary or artistic work sole rights to profit from that work. If inventors are not protected by patents, they would gain little reward from their efforts: as soon as a valuable invention was made public, others would copy it and sell products based on it. And if inventors could not expect to profit from their inventions, then there would be no incentive to incur the costs of invention in the first place. So the law gives a temporary monopoly through imposing temporary property rights that encourage invention and creation


How a Monopolist Maximizes Profit

Why is the marginal revenue from that 10th diamond less than the price? It is less than the price because an increase in production by a monopolist has two opposing effects on revenue:

· A quantity effect. One more unit is sold, increasing total revenue by the price at which the unit is sold.

· A price effect. In order to sell that last unit, the monopolist must cut the market price on all units sold. This decreases total revenue.

 

➤ Due to the price effect of an increase in output, the marginal revenue curve of a firm with market power always lies below its demand curve. So a profit-maximizing monopolist chooses the output level at which marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue—not to price.

➤ as a result,the monopolists produce less and sells its output at a higher price than a perfectly competitive industry would. It earns a profit in the short run and the long run.

 

To emphasize how the quantity and price effects offset each other for a firm with market power, notice that it is hill-shaped total revenue curve.

This reflects the fact that at low levels of output, the quantity effect is stronger than the price effect: as the monopolist sells more, it has to lower the price on only very few units, so the price effect is small.

As output rises beyond 10 diamonds, total revenue actually falls. This reflects the fact that at high levels of output, the price effect is stronger than the quantity effect: as the monopolist sells more, it now has to lower the price on many units of output, making the price effect very large.

 

 


The Monopolist’s Profit-Maximizing Output and Price

P > MR = MC at the monopolist’s profit-maximizing quantity of output

So, just as we suggested earlier, we see that compared with a competitive industry, a monopolist does the following:

■ Produces a smaller quantity: QM < QC

■ Charges a higher price: PM > PC

■ Earns a profit

 

 



barriers to entry allow a monopolist to make profits in both the short run and the long run.

 


Welfare Effects of Monopoly


 

Preventing Monopoly

Policy toward monopoly depends crucially on whether or not the industry in question is a natural monopoly, one in which increasing returns to scale ensure that a bigger producer has lower average total cost. If the industry is not a natural monopoly, the best policy is to prevent monopoly from arising or break it up if it already exists.

The government policies used to prevent or eliminate monopolies are known as antitrust policy

 

Dealing with Natural Monopoly

Breaking up a monopoly that isn’t natural is clearly a good idea: the gains to consumers outweigh the loss to the producer. But it’s not so clear whether a natural monopoly, one in which large producers have lower average total costs than small producers, should be broken up, because this would raise average total cost.

Yet even in the case of a natural monopoly, a profit-maximizing monopolist acts in a way that causes inefficiency—it charges consumers a price that is higher than marginal cost and, by doing so, prevents some potentially beneficial transactions. Also, it can seem unfair that a firm that has managed to establish a monopoly position earns a large profit at the expense of consumers

Public Ownership In many countries, the preferred answer to the problem of natural monopoly has been public ownership. Instead of allowing a private monopolist to control an industry, the government establishes a public agency to provide the good and protect consumers’ interests.

Regulation In the United States, the more common answer has been to leave the industry in private hands but subject it to regulation. In particular, most local utilities are covered by price regulation that limits the prices they can charge.


 

Price Discrimination

 

Up to this point, we have considered only the case of a single-price monopolist, one that charges all consumers the same price. As the term suggests, not all monopolists do this. In fact, many if not most monopolists find that they can increase their profits by charging different customers different prices for the same good: they engage in price discrimination.

 

The important point is that the two groups of consumers differ in their sensitivity to price—that a high price has a larger effect in discouraging purchases by students than by business travelers. As long as different groups of customers respond differently to the price, a monopolist will find that it can capture more consumer surplus and increase its prof- it by charging them different prices.

 

 

1. There are four main types of market structure based on the number of firms in the industry and product differentiation: perfect competition, monopoly, oligopoly, and monopolistic competition.

2. A monopolist is a producer who is the sole supplier of a good without close substitutes. An industry controlled by a monopolist is a monopoly.

3. The key difference between a monopoly and a perfectly competitive industry is that a single perfectly competitive firm faces a horizontal demand curve but a monopolist faces a downward-sloping demand curve. This gives the monopolist market power, the ability to raise the market price by reducing output compared to a perfectly competitive firm.

4. To persist, a monopoly must be protected by a barrier to entry. This can take the form of control of a natural resource or input, increasing returns to scale that give

rise to natural monopoly, technological superiority, or government rules that prevent entry by other firms, such as patents or copyrights.

5. The marginal revenue of a monopolist is composed of a quantity effect (the price received from the additional unit) and a price effect (the reduction in the price at which all units are sold). Because of the price effect, a monopolist’s marginal revenue is always less than the market price, and the marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve.

6. At the monopolist’s profit-maximizing output level, marginal cost equals marginal revenue, which is less than market price. At the perfectly competitive firm’s profit- maximizing output level, marginal cost equals the market price. So in comparison to perfectly competitive industries, monopolies produce less, charge higher prices, and earn profits in both the short run and the long run.

7. A monopoly creates deadweight losses by charging a price above marginal cost: the loss in consumer surplus exceeds the monopolist’s profit. Thus monopolies are a source of market failure and should be prevented or bro- ken up, except in the case of natural monopolies.

8. Natural monopolies can still cause deadweight losses. To limit these losses, governments sometimes impose public ownership and at other times impose price regulation. A price ceiling on a monopolist, as opposed to a perfectly competitive industry, need not cause shortages and can increase total surplus.

9. Not all monopolists are single-price monopolists. Monopolists, as well as oligopolists and monopolistic competitors, often engage in price discrimination to make higher profits, using various techniques to differentiate consumers based on their sensitivity to price and charging those with less elastic demand higher prices. A monopolist that achieves perfect price discrimination charges each consumer a price equal to his or her willingness to pay and captures the total surplus in the mar- ket. Although perfect price discrimination creates no inefficiency, it is practically impossible to implement.

 

OLIGOPOLY

An oligopoly is an industry with only a small number of producers. A producer in such an industry is known as an oligopolist. When no one firm has a monopoly, but producers nonetheless realize that they can affect market prices, an industry is characterized by imperfect competition

An oligopoly consisting of only two firms is a duopoly. Each firm is known as a duopolist.

Sellers engage in collusion when they cooperate to raise their joint profits. A cartel is an agreement among several producers to obey output restrictions in order to increase their joint profits.

When firms ignore the effects of their actions on each others’ profits, they engage in noncooperative behavior

When a firm’s decision significantly affects the profits of other firms in the industry, the firms are in a situation of interdependence.

The study of behavior in situations of interdependence is known as game theory.

The reward received by a player in a game, such as the profit earned by an oligopolist, is that player’s payoff.

A payoff matrix shows how the payoff to each of the participants in a two player game depends on the actions of both. Such a matrix helps us analyze situations of interdependence.

The particular situation shown here is a version of a famous—and seemingly paradoxical—case of interdependence that appears in many contexts. Known as the prisoners’ dilemma, it is a type of game in which the payoff matrix implies the following:

■ Each player has an incentive, regardless of what the other player does, to cheat—to take an action that benefits it at the other’s expense.

■ When both players cheat, both are worse off than they would have been if neither had cheated.

An action is a dominant strategy when it is a player’s best action regardless of the action taken by the other player.

A Nash equilibrium, also known as a noncooperative equilibrium, is the result when each player in a game chooses the action that maximizes his or her payoff given the actions of other players, ignoring the effects of his or her action on the payoffs received by those other players.

A firm engages in strategic behavior when it attempts to influence the future behavior of other firms.

A strategy of tit for tat involves playing cooperatively at first, then doing whatever the other player did in the previous period.

The payoff to ADM of each of these strategies would depend on which strategy Ajinomoto chooses. Consider the four possibilities.

 

1. If ADM plays “tit for tat” and so does Ajinomoto, both firms will make a profit of $180 million each year.

2. If ADM plays “always cheat” but Ajinomoto plays “tit for tat,” ADM makes a profit of $200 million the first year but only $160 million per year thereafter.

3. If ADM plays “tit for tat” but Ajinomoto plays “always cheat,” ADM makes a profit of only $150 million in the first year but $160 million per year thereafter.

4. If ADM plays “always cheat” and Ajinomoto does the same, both firms will make a profit of $160 million each year.

 

When firms limit production and raise prices in a way that raises each others’ profits, even though they have not made any formal agreement, they are engaged in tacit collusion.

An oligopolist who believes she will lose a substantial number of sales if she reduces output and increases her price but will gain only a few additional sales if she increases output and lowers her price, away from the tacit collusion outcome, faces a kinked demand curve — very flat above the kink and very steep below the kink.

Antitrust policy are efforts undertaken by the government to prevent oligopolistic industries from becoming or behaving like monopolies

Although tacit collusion is common, it rarely allows an industry to push prices all the way up to their monopoly level; collusion is usually far from perfect. A variety of factors make it hard for an industry to coordinate on high prices.

·  Large Numbers

· Complex Products and Pricing Schemes

· Differences in Interests

· Bargaining Power of Buyers

 

A price war occurs when tacit collusion breaks down and prices collapse.

  Product differentiation is an attempt by a firm to convince buyers that its product is different from the products of other firms in the industry.

In price leadership, one firm sets its price first, and other firms then follow.

Firms that have a tacit understanding not to compete on price often engage in intense nonprice competition, using advertising and other means to try to increase their sales.


 

1. Many industries are oligopolies: there are only a few sellers. In particular, a duopoly has only two sellers. Oligopolies exist for more or less the same reasons that monopolies exist, but in weaker form. They are character- ized by imperfect competition: firms compete but pos- sess market power.

2. Predicting the behavior of oligopolists poses something of a puzzle. The firms in an oligopoly could maximize their combined profits by acting as a cartel, setting out- put levels for each firm as if they were a single monopo- list; to the extent that firms manage to do this, they engage in collusion. But each individual firm has an incentive to produce more than it would in such an arrangement—to engage in noncooperative behavior. Informal collusion is likely to be easier to achieve in industries in which firms face capacity constraints.

3. The situation of interdependence, in which each firm’s profit depends noticeably on what other firms do, is the subject of game theory. In the case of a game with two players, the payoff of each player depends both on its own actions and on the actions of the other; this inter- dependence can be represented as a payoff matrix. Depending on the structure of payoffs in the payoff matrix, a player may have a dominant strategy—an action that is always the best regardless of the other play- er’s actions.

4. Duopolists face a particular type of game known as a prisoners’ dilemma; if each acts independently in its own interest, the resulting Nash equilibrium or nonco- operative equilibrium will be bad for both. However, firms that expect to play a game repeatedly tend to engage in strategic behavior, trying to influence each other’s future actions. A particular strategy that seems to work well in such situations is tit for tat, which often leads to tacit collusion.

5. The kinked demand curve illustrates how an oligopolist that faces unique changes in its marginal cost within a certain range may choose not to adjust its output and price in order to avoid a breakdown in tacit collusion.

6. In order to limit the ability of oligopolists to collude and act like monopolists, most governments pursue an antitrust policy designed to make collusion more diffi- cult. In practice, however, tacit collusion is widespread.

7. A variety of factors make tacit collusion difficult: large numbers of firms, complex products and pricing, differ- ences in interests, and bargaining power of buyers. When tacit collusion breaks down, there is a price war. Oligopolists try to avoid price wars in various ways, such as through product differentiation and through price leadership, in which one firm sets prices for the indus- try. Another is through nonprice competition, like advertising.

 

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION

Monopolistic competition is a market structure in which

· there are many competing producers in an industry,

· each producer sells a differentiated product,

· there is free entry into and exit from the industry in the long run.

Product differentiation plays an even more crucial role in monopolistically competitive industries.

Why?

Tacit collusion is virtually impossible when there are many producers. Hence, product differentiation is the only way monopolistically competitive firms can acquire some market power.

How do firms in the same industry- such as fast-food vendors, gas stations, or chocolate companies- differentiate their products?

Is the difference mainly in the minds of consumers or in the products themselves?

There are 3 important forms of product differentiation:

· Differentiation by Style or Type – sedans vs SUVs

· Differentiation by Location – dry cleaner near home vs cheaper dry cleaner far away

· Differentiation by Quality – ordinary chocolate vs gourmet chocolate

Whatever form it takes, however, there are two important features of industries with differentiated products:

· Competition among sellers means that even though sellers of differentiated products are not offering identical goods, they are to some extent competing for a limited market. If more businesses enter the market, each will find that it sells less quantity at any given price.

· Value in diversity. Benefits to consumers from a greater diversity of available products.

As the term monopolistic competition suggests, this market structure combines some features typical of monopoly with others typical of perfect competition:

· Because each firm is offering a distinct product, it is in a way like a monopolist: it faces a downward-sloping demand curve and has some market power—the ability within limits to determine the price of its product.

· However, unlike a pure monopolist, a monopolistically competitive firm does face competition: the amount of its product it can sell depends on the prices and products offered by other firms in the industry.

The following figure shows two possible situations that a typical firm in a monopolistically competitive industry might face in the short run.

· In each case, the firm looks like any monopolist: it faces a downward-sloping demand curve, which implies a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve.

·
 

We assume that every firm has an upward-sloping marginal cost curve but that it also faces some fixed costs, so that its average total cost curve is U-shaped.

 

 

If existing firms are profitable, entry will occur and shift each existing firm’s demand curve left- ward. If existing firms are unprofitable, each remaining firm’s demand curve shifts rightward as some firms exit the industry.


in long-run zero-profit equilibrium, the demand curve of each firm is tangent to its average total cost curve at its profit-maximizing quantity.

In the long-run equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive industry, there are many firms, all earning zero profit.

 

Price exceeds marginal cost so some mutually beneficial trades are exploited.

Firms in a monopolistically competitive industry have excess capacity: they produce less than the output at which average total cost is minimized.

Price exceeds marginal cost, so some mutually beneficial trades are unexploited.

The higher price consumers pay because of excess capacity is offset to some extent by the value they receive from greater diversity.


Hence it is not clear the this is actually a source of inefficiency.

No discussion of product differentiation is complete without spending at least a bit of time on the two related issues:

· advertising

· brand names.

In industries with product differentiation, firms advertise in order to increase the demand for their products.

Advertising is not a waste of resources when it gives consumers useful information about products.

Advertising that simply touts a product is harder to explain.

Either consumers are irrational, or expensive advertising communicates that the firm’s products are of high quality.

 


Some firms create brand names.

A brand name is a name owned by a particular firm that distinguishes its products from those of other firms.

As with advertising, the economic value of brand names can be ambiguous.

They convey real information when they assure consumers of the quality of a product.

 

1.Monopolistic competition is a market structure in which there are many competing producers, each produc-

ing a differentiated product, and there is free entry and

exit in the long run. Product differentiation takes three

main forms: by style or type, by location, or by quality. Products of competing sellers are considered imperfect substitutes, and each firm has its own downward-sloping demand curve and marginal revenue curve.

2. Short-run profits will attract entry of new firms in the long run. This reduces the quantity each existing produc-

er sells at any given price and shifts its demand curve to

the left. Short-run losses will induce exit by some firms

in the long run. This shifts the demand curve of each remaining firm to the right.

3. In the long run, a monopolistically competitive industry is in zero-profit equilibrium: at its profit-maximizing quantity, the demand curve for each existing firm is tan- gent to its average total cost curve. There are zero profits in the industry and no entry or exit.

4. In long-run equilibrium, firms in a monopolistically competitive industry sell at a price greater than marginal cost. They also have excess capacity because they pro- duce less than the minimum-cost output; as a result, they have higher costs than firms in a perfectly competi- tive industry. Whether or not monopolistic competition is inefficient is ambiguous because consumers value the diversity of products that it creates.

5. A monopolistically competitive firm will always prefer to make an additional sale at the going price, so it will engage in advertising to increase demand for its product and enhance its market power. Advertising and brand names that provide useful information to consumers are economically valuable. But they are economically waste- ful when their only purpose is to create market power.

In reality, advertising and brand names are likely to be some of both: economically valuable and economically wasteful.

 

EXTERNALITIES

Pollution is a bad thing.

· Yet most pollution is a side effect of activities that provide us with good things.

· our air is polluted by power plants generating the electricity that lights our cities, and our rivers are damaged by fertilizer runoff from farms that grow our food.

Pollution is a side effect of useful activities, so the optimal quantity of pollution isn’t zero.

The marginal social cost of pollution is the additional cost imposed on society as a whole by an additional unit of pollution.

The marginal social benefit of pollution is the additional gain to society as a whole from an additional unit of pollution.

The socially optimal quantity of pollution is the quantity of pollution that society would choose if all the costs and benefits of pollution were fully accounted for.

An external cost is an uncompensated cost that an individual or firm imposes on others.

An external benefit is a benefit that an individual or firm confers on others without receiving compensation.

 

Pollution is an example of an external cost, or negative externality; in contrast, some activities can give rise to external benefits, or positive externalities. External costs and benefits are known as externalities.

 

Left to itself, a market economy will typically generate too much pollution because polluters have no incentive to take into account the costs they impose on others.

 

In an influential 1960 article, the economist Ronald Coase pointed out that, in an ideal world, the private sector could indeed deal with all externalities.

According to the Coase theorem, even in the presence of externalities an economy can always reach an efficient solution provided that the transaction costs—the costs to individuals of making a deal—are sufficiently low.

The costs of making a deal are known as transaction costs.

 

The implication of Coase’s analysis is that externalities need not lead to inefficiency because individuals have an incentive to find a way to make mutually beneficial deals that lead them to take externalities into account when making decisions.

When individuals do take externalities into account, economists say that they internalize the externality.

Transaction costs prevent individuals from making efficient deals.

 

Examples of transaction costs include the following:

  • The costs of communication among the interested parties—costs that may be very high if many people are involved.
  • The costs of making legally binding agreements that may be high if doing so requires the employment of expensive legal services.
  • Costly delays involved in bargaining—even if there is a potentially beneficial deal, both sides may hold out in an effort to extract more favorable terms, leading to increased effort and forgone utility.

 

Policies Toward Pollution:

· Environmental standards are rules that protect the environment by specifying actions by producers and consumers. Generally such standards are inefficient because they are inflexible.

· An emissions tax is a tax that depends on the amount of pollution a firm produces.

· Tradable emissions permits are licenses to emit limited quantities of pollutants that can be bought and sold by polluters.

· Taxes designed to reduce external costs are known as Pigouvian taxes.

 

  • When the quantity of pollution emitted can be directly observed and controlled, environmental goals can be achieved efficiently in two ways: emissions taxes and tradable emissions permits.
  • These methods are efficient because they are flexible, allocating more pollution reduction to those who can do it more cheaply.
  • An emissions tax is a form of Pigouvian tax, a tax designed to reduce external costs.
  • The optimal Pigouvian tax is equal to the marginal social cost of pollution at the socially optimal quantity of pollution.

 

  • When there are external costs, the marginal social cost of a good or activity exceeds the industry’s marginal cost of producing the good.
  • In the absence of government intervention, the industry typically produces too much of the good.
  • The socially optimal quantity can be achieved by an optimal Pigouvian tax, equal to the marginal external cost, or by a system of tradable production permits.

 

 

The marginal social benefit of a good or activity is equal to the marginal benefit that accrues to consumers plus its marginal external benefit.

A Pigouvian subsidy is a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits.

A technology spillover is an external benefit that results when knowledge spreads among individuals and firms. The socially optimal quantity can be achieved by an optimal Pigouvian subsidy equal to the marginal external benefit.

An industrial policy is a policy that supports industries believed to yield positive externalities.

 

The marginal social cost of a good or activity is equal to the marginal cost of production plus its marginal external cost.

 

A good is subject to a network externality when the value of the good to an individual is greater when a large number of other people also use the good.

Any way in which other people’s consumption of a good increases your own marginal benefit from consumption of that good can give rise to network effects.

A good is subject to positive feedback when success breeds greater success and failure breeds failure.

 



Поделиться:


Последнее изменение этой страницы: 2021-07-19; просмотров: 215; Нарушение авторского права страницы; Мы поможем в написании вашей работы!

infopedia.su Все материалы представленные на сайте исключительно с целью ознакомления читателями и не преследуют коммерческих целей или нарушение авторских прав. Обратная связь - 18.224.63.87 (0.227 с.)